Roger Garrison’s Time
and Money lays out explicitly the Austrian Business Cycle Theory with a focus on the impact of central bank
intervention. His exposition is clear. In fact, so clear that it lays out a
fundamental weakness in the theory. In the chapter title, “Sustainable and
Unsustainable Growth”, Garrison argues booms funded by an increase in real
savings don’t result in resource misallocation.
The market works. But just how the intertemporal markets work requires that we shift our attention to the intertemporal structure of production. The altered shape of the Hayekian triangle shows just how the additional investment funds are used. The rate of interest governs the intertemporal pattern of investment as well as the overall level. The lower interst rate, which is reflected in the more shallow slope of the triangle’s hypotenuse, favors relatively long-term investments. Resources are bid away from late stages of production, where demand is weak because of the currently low consumption, and into early stages, where demand is strong because of the lower rate of interest. That is, if the marginal increment of investment in early stages was just worthwhile, given the costs of borrowing, then additional increments will be seen as worthwhile, given the new, lower costs of borrowing. While many firms are simply reacting to the spread between their output prices and their input prices in the light of the reduced cost of borrowing, the general pattern of intertemporal restructuring is consistent with an anticipation of a strengthened future demand for consumption goods made possible by the increased saving. (64)
Garrison presents us with the beginning state, interest
rates drop, and guides us to the end state, claiming that credit markets
reallocate resources from the late stages of production to the earlier stages
of production. Boom. There you have it. Interest rates coordinate production
and markets adjust. But just how does this occur? This is a challenging
question for Austrians who do not believe that business cycles can occur
endogenously (not to suggest that this is the case for all Austrians).
The process of bidding away resources from the late stages
of production does not occur smoothly. Let us imagine that the interest rate
has dropped and new profit opportunities arise because there is a discrepancy
between the rate of return for the new project and the rate of interest.
Entrepreneurs will flock to the new opportunity. The more attractive the
opportunity, the greater the number of entrepreneurs who will pursue the
project. The entrepreneurs know that they are competing against other
entrepreneurs and that not everyone can be successful in this endeavor.
Likewise, banks provide credit to entrepreneurs that they believe will be
successful. Again, the banks are aware that not every investment in this new
opportunity will succeed, but they hope to do better than their competitors by allocating
loans wisely and operating efficiently.
With the passage of time, entrepreneurs either reap rewards
for their success or losses for their failure. The rise of the interest rate
from increased demand for loanable funds and the fall in the rate of return on
the new projects from the increase in entrepreneurial activity make this
scenario unavoidable. There will be failure and it will occur under conditions
where all actors are profit maximizing. If there was significant interest in
the sector where the new investment opportunity arose, there may also be
significant levels of failure, especially if the sector is highly competitive.
We can expect that, alongside bankruptcies, prices in the sector will fall and
credit will tighten due to debt-deflation. That is, bankruptcies will decrease
the amount of funds available in the sector. Eventually, these assets will be
bought by successful firms or new entrepreneurs at lower prices.
Thus, we have the formation of a business cycle without central bank intervention. This
is not to suggest that central bank intervention in credit markets cannot
encourage bubbles to be larger and more numerous, only that this should be the starting point of a business cycle theory. As Joseph Schumpeter argued
in “The Explanation of the Business Cycle”,
…is it not imperative to develop
for the purposes of fundamental explanation an analysis independent of the
occurrence of impulses from without – an analysis of the way in which new
things come to be done in industrial life, and old methods come to be
eliminated together with those firms who cannot rise above them? (297)
It is imperative that we have an endogenous theory of the
cycle as our starting point. This is a story where low interest rates induced
from increased savings encourages a boom and subsequent bust. Garrison’s model
does not allow for this. It suggests that markets transition smoothly from one
state to the next as long as changes in the interest rate are produced endogenously.
That is, the change in the
underlying economic realities imply an altered growth path; the market process
translates the technological advance into the new preferred growth path; and there is nothing in the nature of this
market process that turns the process against itself. (60)
Nothing to turn the process against itself? Nothing except
the entrepreneur. Nothing except competition and failure. Markets fail. That is
the beauty of markets.
No comments:
Post a Comment