Many Austrian economists are skeptical of the efficacy of a
nominal income level targeting policy for a central bank. For example, Alex Salter argues that nominal income (he discusses NGDP) should not be treated as an
object of choice for central bankers. His perception that nominal income level
targeting treats nominal income as an object of choice is representative of a widespread Austrian critique concerning prices and the role they play. The argument misses important nuance
in comparing fiat regimes with hard money regimes. Given that the target is predicted by a futures market, it is not actually an object of choice. The central bank would not attempt to determine nominal income. Instead, it would respond to the best estimation of aggregate demand available. (That the target inflation rate is an object of choice is up for debate. For now I will assume that there is no inflation target embedded in the policy.) In this post, I will confront this objection by analyzing the mechanisms through which a regime that targets nominal income would function. I will also confront other objections as necessary.
Nominal income level targeting is a policy suggestion that
unfolds from Say’s law. In a market where there is an excess supply of goods,
there is an excess demand for money (Clower and Leijonhufvud 1973; Yeager 1956). That is, nominal cash balances are not high enough to clear all markets at curent prices. Under a gold standard, increases in demand for money lead to an
endogenous increase in the money stock. This increase is not instantaneous as
the supply of gold is relatively inelastic. Nor are these changes in the gold
stock neutral. The economic effects of the entry of this money depend on the
injection point – i.e., where is the gold first spent or deposited? It is true
that under a pure free banking system, the injection point is guided by real
demand. It is also true that the endogenous mechanisms that guided the
production of base money – gold – do not exist under the modern system of fiat
currencies. The primary endogenous mechanism of money creation available under the
present system is credit expansion. In markets where there are excess supplies
of goods, the creation of credit helps clear these markets. Without a similar
endogenous mechanism for the creation of base money, demand deficiencies are
more likely to persist. Despite the objection from Salter that nominal income
is an outcome and should not be targeted by the monetary authority, the lack of
an endogenous mechanism to control the base money stock makes a nominal income
level targeting regime necessary.
Whether or not the central bank practices nominal income
level targeting, the fact remains that the central bank still operates. We should not be given to the “Nirvana Fallacy.”
Salter admits that nominal income level targeting might be preferable to the
current regime. I think there is theoretical reason for fully embracing the
norm. (I don’t have an answer for the public choice critiques at this time, so
my defense concentrates on monetary theory.) The choice for policy makers is not between
a free banking system and a system with a central bank. There is no policy
choice that leaves the central bank on the sideline to do nothing in our
present world of fiat currency regimes. We must ask, then, which policy will
minimize nominal distortions? Which policy will promote healthy, flexible credit markets that can neutralize
problems stemming from monetary disequilibrium?
Economic analysis allows us to imagine what an ideal regime
would look like. As Hayek argued in Pricesand Production, MV stabilization is a theoretical ideal, but that ideal
includes not just some aggregate stabilization. Monetary injections are
provided at precisely the points where demand for money has increased. Such a
norm is impossible for a central bank to implement directly. It is for this
reason that Selgin and White promote a free banking standard under which the
money stock responds to changes in demand for fiduciary currency (White 1999; Selginand White 1994). What is not typically appreciated in the argument about nominal
income level targeting is that this policy norm would also be aided by financial intermediaries whose actions help stabilize nominal income much like in the Selgin and White free banking model.
Nominal income level targeting is not, on its own, an
economic panacea. Expansion of the money stock always has non-neutral effects.
Since injections occur through the financial sector, injections will affect interest
rates. This is not as big of a shortcoming as the critics of nominal income
level targeting claim it is. If the money stock is insufficient to meet the
demands implied by expected nominal income, then we can expect interest rates
to rise as an elevated demand for money does not allow markets to clear. As heightened
demand for liquidity pushes up interest rates in this manner, all else equal, the
market rate of interest is pushed above the natural
rate which is the rate that reflects time preference. Credit markets are in
disequilibrium.
In the case of disequilibrium, an expansion that offsets MV
serves the same role that gold flows and gold production did under the gold
standard. The difference is that the response of the base money stock to changes
in demand for money occurs much more rapidly than it did under the gold
standard. The employment of a nominal income futures market will allow the
adjustment of the monetary base to offset changes in liquidity preference that
affect credit markets in a way that emulates the response of the base money
stock to changes in demand for money under a gold standard.
As mentioned above, monetary expansion by the Federal
Reserve is channeled through the financial sectors. Some may voice objections
relating to the channel of expansion (Selgin 2012). The Federal Reserve expands
the money stock by buying from and selling to primary dealers of securities.
Selgin correctly argues that confronting this problem will promote stability. Similarly,
some worry that the policy will have asymmetric effects in different geographic
regions and that efficient markets hypothesis will not hold with respect to the
NGDP futures market (Murphy 2013). I agree with the first proposition, but even
under the current circumstances, the alleviation of a general excess demand for
money will be more stabilizing than the next best option, whether or not the
allocation of the expansion of the base is improved. If I am
right that nominal income targeting will help offset distortions in the
interest rate caused by liquidity preference, I do not believe the first
objection is problematic. The implementation Selgin’s policy suggestions would
certainly improve a nominal income targeting regime! Nor are the other objections fatal to the efficacy of nominal income targeting. My response to these require elaboration.
Markets can handle small shocks quite well. It is in the
face of large negative shocks that are self feeding – for example, a scenario
of heavy deflation that makes credit markets dysfunctional, thus leading to
further deflation – that markets have difficulty remaining anywhere close to the
expected nominal income growth path. To be more specific, under a scenario of
heavy deflation, both goods markets and intertemporal markets fail to clear as
a rise in demand for money constrains liquidity. Bad central bank policy, like
that of the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve leading into the Great
Depression, can destabilize the economy and lead to such a situation. Under a
nominal income targeting regime, problem caused by fluctuations in money demand
are alleviated. Dramatic fluctuations in nominal income due to changes in money
demand will be prevented. The shocks that are most damaging to the functioning
of a healthy economy are neutralized. Even better, monetary policy that
promotes this sort of disequilibrium - much like gold hoarding policies of the Great Depression - are not allowed under a nominal income
targeting rule.
So what of the significance of inaccuracies of expectations
and asymmetric demand for money? The critics are correct that no measure is
perfect. So long as the futures market actually reflects nominal income within
a limited margin of error, credit markets can adjust the money stock for these small
perturbations. The beauty of nominal income targeting is that it ensures that
the credit market will be able to function, and thereby offset these problems. By
increasing the base money stock and thereby aiding liquidity, a nominal income level
target promotes more robust credit markets that can adjust the broader money
stock to conform to particular circumstances not accounted for by the
employment of the equation of exchange. In
this sense, nominal income targeting and free banking should not be thought of
as totally distinct. The endogenous response of the money stock that is at the core of free banking theory is very much present in modern credit markets. Without a well functioning credit sector, nominal income level targeting falls short of its goal.
Final thought: A nominal income level target requires a credible commitment from the central bank to not bail insolvent institutions. This is where the public choice critique must be answered.
No comments:
Post a Comment