Banking
When
money first arises, agents must find a way to economize on cash balances.
Agents can hold on to commodities, but this is a risky practice. Commodity
money may deteriorate or be lost or stolen. Theft was especially a problem for
those making long trips through the countryside. Holding on to cash balances is
costly. Early on, agents realize this. Those with enough wealth begin to keep
their money with a trusted third party. Historically, when gold came into use
as money, agents left their gold at a warehouse in exchange for a deposit slip.
These deposit slips served a role as a medium of exchange. If the warehouse has
multiple branches, the deposit slips might be exchanged at another branch, thus
increasing the marketability of the slips by diminishing agents’ incentive to
discount the them. These slips are part of a more general class of money known
as fiduciary currency (the root of the word fiduciary comes from the Latin word
for “faith”). These are promises to repay.
Eventually,
the keepers of the warehouses realize that they can lend the money entrusted to
them so long as depositors do not rush all at once to retrieve their commodity
money. This is fractional reserve banking. Banks hold some portion of their
reserves (the money lent to them) while lending the remainder. This allows cash
to be employed when it would otherwise sit in reserve. For depositors, this
diminishes the cost of holding cash balances. In a gold standard world, for
example, instead of holding and exchanging in actual gold, agents can exchange
deposit slips. Meanwhile, they earn interest on the money that they have
temporarily relinquished to the bank. This creates a tendency for the total
money stock, which in our example is the total gold plus the total amount of deposit slips to fluctuate due to changes
in demand to hold currency. We measure the relative size of the total money
supply by comparing the base money stock to the total amount of money in
circulation.
MB=
MT / MM
or
MM = MT / MB
or
MM = MT / MB
Where:
MT = Total Money Stock (MB + Liquid Credit Instruments)
MB = Base Money
MM = Money Multiplier
The money multiplier is intimately related to the reserve ratio of a banking system. Collectively, banks form an aggregate reserve ratio. It is defined by the amount of
currency they have on hand divided by their total liabilities. Monetary
dynamics fall out of this identity. When banks extend credit on net, the
reserve ratio drops. When banks contract credit on net, the ratio increases.
When agents deposit currency on net, the ratio increases. When agents withdraw
currency on net, the ratio falls (Hawtrey 1919).
We might also think of the reserve ratio as its inverse: the
money multiplier. This represents the ratio of total currency to base currency.
The ratio of currency to deposits plays an important role in this identity as it
allows us to observe the effect of a change in currency or deposits on the
money multiplier.
Mt = C + D
Mb = C + R
Mt/Mb = (C + D) / (C + R)
Mt/Mb = (C/D + 1) / (C/D + r)
Where:
Mt / Mb = Money Multiplier
C = Currency
D = Deposit
*Other variables defined as above
Notice that the numerator is larger than the denominator as
long as r < 1. This means that as C increases, the denominator grows at a
faster rate than the numerator. The money multiplier falls under this scenario.
Likewise, as the total stock of currency shrinks, the money multiplier grows.
Similarly, as the amount of deposits increases, the denominator, C/D + r, falls at a faster rate than the numerator. The money multiplier increases. As deposits
falls, the money multiplier falls.
Unspent Margin: Cash Balances, Money on Account, and Substituting for Available Credit Lines
Agents respond to the incentives of this relatively flexible
system. We assume that agents economize on cash balances. That is, they decide
to hold cash for several reasons. Agents receive income in discrete units, so
they must build up reserves in preparation for periods where income has yet to
be received. Agents also hold currency or deposit balances in order to hedge
for risk. Last, agents deposit their currency in discrete quantities. (This was
more important before the development of direct deposit and electronic
quasi-monies.) Agents may economize on cash balances by leaving their money on
deposit to collect interest. They may also choose to allot some wealth to
long-term investments where it collects more interest than an ordinary demand
deposit account. They may also choose to substitute an available credit line
for balances of cash or deposits. By doing this, an agent may collect a higher
yield from long-term investments while still having ample liquidity to deal
with fluctuations in their own demand for money.
The unspent margin serves as analytical proxy for demand for
money. First we must identify the unspent margin. “The unspent margin is equal
to all the cash, whether in circulation or in the banks, plus the net interest bearing assets of the banks
(Hawtrey 1919).” The unspent margin represents portfolio demand for money. In a
world where credit influences the money stock, a net increase in loans by the
banks will first have the effect of increasing the unspent margin. When credit
is expanded without being exchanged for goods, the credit represents an increase
in the money stock with an offsetting expenditure. Demand for money increases
(velocity falls) as a result. A contraction of credit represent a fall in
demand for money. Demand for money falls as agents relinquish cash to the bank
and the bank fails to offset the decrease in liabilities. In either case, prices
must adjust to in order to facilitate the exchange despite a change in the
money stock.
It is from this pattern that Hawtrey made an observation concerning
the relation between incomes and changes in credit.
Apart from this shuffling of debts,
all the credit created is created for the purposes of being paid away in the
form of profits, wages, salaries, interest, rents – in fact, to provide the
incomes of all who contribute, by their services or their property, to the
process of production, production being taken in the widest sense to include
whatever produces value. It is for the expenses of production, in this wide
sense, that people borrow, and it is of these payments that the expenses of
production consist. So we reach the conclusion that an acceleration or
retardation of the creation of credit means an equal increase or decrease in
people’s incomes.
In the world that we have constructed thus far, exchange
only occurs when both agents expect to profit. This implies an expectation of
the lender that the borrower has or will earn the means to repay the loan at a
later date. The borrower will typically produce goods or provide services in
order to raise the income required for repayment. In a world of voluntary
exchange, then, incomes rise and fall with increases and decreases of the
credit stock as this reflects changes in the expected value of production.
No comments:
Post a Comment