In particular, socialist thought owes its appeal to the
young largely to its visionary character; the very courage to indulge in Utopian
thought is in this respect a source of strength to the socialists which
traditional liberalism sadly lacks. He closes the article by arguing:
We must make the building of a free society once more an intellectual adventure, a deed of courage. What we lack is a liberal Utopia, a program which seems neither a mere defense of things as they are nor a diluted kind of socialism, but a truly liberal radicalism which does not spare the susceptibilities of the mighty (including the trade unions), which is not too severely practical, and which does not confine itself to what appears today as politically possible.
During the Great Depression
Hayek had struggled to convince his colleagues of the merits of certain classical
liberal tenants that he valued. He failed to sway their opinion concerning the gold
standard. This was also true concerning the Austrian Business Cycle Theory. He only
partly succeeded in disillusioning them of their socialist utopian dreams with
his participation in the Socialist Calculation Debate. Where had Hayek gone
wrong? Hayek’s remarks in “Intellectuals and Socialism” about utopianism appear
to be confession. He had not been idealistic enough.
Written before “Intellectuals
and Socialism” in 1943, Hayek’s “A Commodity Reserve Currency” represents a shift
in his research program where he begins to stress future avenues to prosperity
and political organization, rather than a propose solutions that might be
interpreted as “a mere defense of things as they are.” It is a truly symbolic of
this change in that he moves from criticizing price level stabilization to
proposing not only how it might successfully operate, but how the rules of its
operations my mitigate the extreme fluctuations of the business cycle. His
proposal is not the same as his peers. He suggests that, rather than having the
price level be stabilized by changes in the money stock that offset changes in
velocity, the use of a commodity reserves can stabilize the general price of
commodities directly by setting a fixed exchange rate for commodities which
will increase demand for them when prices fall below the fixed rate and alleviate
demand when prices rise above the fixed rate:
With this [commodity] system in operation an increase in the demand for liquid assets would lead to the accumulation of stocks of raw commodities of the most general usefulness. As the hoarded money was again returned to circulation, and demand for commodities increased these stock would be released to satisfy the new demand.
He explains how this will
dampen the business cycle:
The revival of activity will not lead to an extra stimulus to the production of raw commodities which would continue on an even keel. There is reason to regard the temporary stimulus of excessive expansion of production to raw commodities, which used to be given by the sharp rise of their prices in boom periods, as one of the most serious causes of general instability. This would be entirely avoided under the proposed scheme – at least so long as the monetary authority had any stocks from which to sell.
This represents an about
face from the direction of much of his previous work. His critique of price
level stabilization and promotion of the gold standard during the 1930s had
apparently gained Hayek few followers. The western world had suffered tragedy
twice within two decades – first with the Great War, then the Great Depression –
and the zeitgeist of the era did not look to the past for future success.
Intellectuals craved idealism, not recitation of former creeds. They wanted swift
change and saw the state as the vehicle for that change. Hayek learned that if
the liberal values that he promoted were to survive, he needed to propose policies
that were a radical departure for the past. The new vision must present
previously unrealized solutions that constrain, rather than empower, the state.
This new program is well exemplified in a couple passages of his 1943 article
where he stresses the importance of rules:
There would, in particular, be no need for the monetary authorities or the government in any way directly to handle the many commodities of which the commodity unit is composed. Both the bringing-together of the required assortment of warrants and the actual storing of the commodities could be safely left to private initiative. Specialist brokers would soon take care of the collecting and tendering of warrants as soon as their aggregate market price fell ever so little below the standard figure and of withdrawing and redistributing the warrants to their various markets if their aggregate prices rose above that figure. In this respect the business of the monetary authority would be as mechanical as the buying and selling of gold under the gold standard.
And:
Even apart from monetary consideration, the great need is for a system under which these controls are taken from the separate bodies which can but act in what is essentially an arbitrary and unpredictable manner and to make the controls instead subject to a mechanical and predictable rule.
We can certainly see the
roots of Hayek’s later work on spontaneous order as Hayek suggested rules that
might procure stability that allows economic agents to make plans and
coordinate them with others.