In his 1936
treatise, Keynes formulated Say’s Law as proposing that “supply creates its own
demand.” It is not clear exactly what Keynes meant by this. The statement
implies an assumption of equilibrium where all excess demands are zero. That
is, if supply creates its own demand, then quantity demanded of a good and the
quantity supplied must be equal. This is at worst a misrepresentation of Say’s
Identity and at best an incoherent statement that appeared in one of the most
popular economics treatises in history.
What is
Say’s Law and why does it matter? In A Treatise on Political Economy, Say argues
A man who applies his labour to the investing of objects with value by the creation of utility of some sort, can not expect such a value to be appreciated and paid for, unless where other men have the means of purchasing it. Now, of what means do these consist? Of other values of other products, likewise the fruits of industry, capital, and land. Which leads us to a conclusion that may at first sight appear paradoxical, namely, that it is production which opens a demand for products.
Ultimately, goods must pay for goods. If an agent wishes to
purchase a product, he or she must either exchange another good directly for
the desired good or else acquire by exchange money to purchase the item. Confusion
arises when money must be integrated into the framework. Unfortunately, Say
does not do a good job of explaining the significance of money within this
schema.
Thus, to say that sales are dull
owing to the scarcity of money, is to mistake the means for the cause; an error
that proceeds from the circumstance, that almost all produce is in the first
instance exchanged for money, before it is ultimately converted into other
produce: and the commodity, which recurs so repeatedly in use, appears to
vulgar apprehensions the most important of commodities, and the end object of
all transactions, whereas it is only the medium. Sales cannot be said to be
dull because money is scarce, but because other products are so. Should the
increase of traffic require more money to facilitate it, the want is easily supplied,
and is a strong indication of prosperity – a proof that a great abundance off
values has been created, which it is wished to exchange for other values.
Say’s description implies that he understands that there can
be an excess demand for money that raises money's price. That increase in price will
encourage an increase in the available money stock. Having brushed off the
problem of insufficient demand by relying on an invisible-hand process, Say
give a less than satisfactory supply-side argument for explaining general
gluts.
It is because the production of
some commodities has declined, that other commodities are superabundant. To use
a more hackneyed phrase, people have bought less, because they have made less
profit; and they made less profit for one or two causes; either they have found
difficulties in the employment of their productive means, or these means have
themselves been deficient.
Say describes here a misallocation of resources that only
adjustment of price, and subsequently, of the capital structure can fix. It is
possible however, that the processes that coordinate market activity might be
interrupted by extreme swings in demand for money. It is this problem for which
Leijonhufvud and Clower’s extension of Say’s Law as “Say’s Principle” (they
refer to it as SP) provides a clear explanation.
Leijonhufvud
and Clower describe Say’s Principle first in terms of individual agents. The
core of their claim goes that “the net
value of an individual’s planned trades is identically zero.” Individual
agents make decisions concerning the allocation of their money. An agent may
decide to spend all available money on goods and hold no cash on hand or he may
decide to withhold some amount of money for safe-keeping. In the latter case,
the agent has a positive portfolio demand for money. Algebraically, the authors
represent this elementary budget constraint in a system of exchange where such a constraint is implied by secure property rights:
Pxdx
+ pydy + dm– sm,0 = 0
In order for an individual's plans to be coherent, planned expenditures plus planned holdings of money (portfolio demand) must equal the stock of money available to the agent. The authors explain further in terms of common interpretations,
‘No one plans to supply anything of
value without also planning some use for the proceeds from the sale, which may
include simply planning to hold money until a later decision is made to
purchase other commodities.’ This statement is correct and sensible.”
‘Confronted with given prices, each
transactor must plan to supply commodities of sufficient value to finance all
his planned net demands.’ This statement is also correct.
If you have not intuited this by now, Say’s Principle
is simply an observation of agent action given a budget constraint.
When
money is not included as the “mth commodity”, it is possible that excess
supplies of goods can exist. However, when money is included we find that all
excess supplies are equally offset by excess demands for goods. This is of
special significance if one is to understand macroeconomic fluctuations.
Distortionary representations of Say’s Principle connect the identity to an
equilibrium assumption. This seems to be what Keynes was implying. Say’s
Principle does not imply equilibrium absent a process to correct expectations. SP is an observation. Movement toward equilibrium requires some minimum
threshold of convergent expectations amongst the population of agents as well as
some combination of flexible prices and an endogenous money stock.
Money is
different from all other goods in that it comprises one side of every monetary
exchange. For this reason, we may separate economic goods into two categories
for the sake of analysis. There is 1) money and then there are 2) all other
goods. The value of goods in the second category are enumerated in a given currency
unit. An excess supply of any good occurs when agents plan, in aggregate, to
purchase less of the commodity than is available at a given price. This leads,
by definition, to an excess demand for the “mth” good, money, meaning that at given
the current constellation of prices, agents demand more money than is
available. This will tend to push the price of money – the amount of goods that
money exchanges for – upward and, conversely, the prices of commodities
downward. This does not mean that the price of all commodities will necessarily
fall, but that there will be deflationary pressure as the real stock of money
(M/P) is others unable to facilitate exchange of goods until either prices have
fallen or the nominal money stock (just M) rises. Until the problem is
corrected, there will be a fall in output and employment of both labor.
We can illustrate
Say’s principle with graphs of the money stock and of aggregate supply and
demand. Those of you reading last week should recognize these graphs.
This represents an economy where agents have elected to
increase the nominal value of their dollar holdings. Before prices adjust to
reflect this change, there will be 1) and excess demand for money and 2) an excess
supply of goods. Not enough money exists to facilitate exchange until prices
drop. Eventually, prices must drop in order to clear available inventories. If
the general fall in prices takes an extended period of time to occur, then
there will be a depression: an extended fall in real output. This comes with an
increase in unemployment and a fall in living standards for those agents not
prepared for the depression.
Two
solutions to this problem have been discussed. Either prices can fall to
alleviate growing inventories or the money stock can increase. This has policy
implications. 1) A central bank can attempt to alleviate, either in whole or in
part, fluctuations in demand for money. The most popular formulation of this
proposal is that the central bank should attempt to stabilize MV by adjusting M
to offset changes in V. Leijonhufvud and Clower note some historical skepticism
about this approach:
. . . Its use raises other issues.
To whom is ‘the engine of inflation’ to be entrusted? What limits to that party’s
discretionary use of the throttle would it be advisable to impose? . . .
Reliance on the automatic solution, in this [classical] view, is argued to be
the lesser of two evils.
Perhaps a better solution to this problem is to enact
policies that enable the money stock to automatically fluctuate according to
changes in demand for it. This might include the removal, or at least
minimization, of barriers to liquidity that discourage asset owners from converting
those assets into cash (i.e., the capital gains tax and legal restrictions applied
to particular classes of assets). Another significant element in promoting a
robust economy is the facilitation of expectation formation in regard to public
policy. Government agencies are “Big Players” whose plans and actions are considered by
agents in the formation of their own expectations (Koppl 2002). If “Big Players” act
unpredictably, agents will be less able to coordinate. If these “Big Players”
are unable to accommodate this need due to the nature of the political process,
then there may be a case for a shrinking of the scope of influence for these
government agencies. Of course, this is not to deny that it is possible that
changes in government structure might also accommodate this need, but this is
even more difficult of a task to accomplish.
I leave you with Say’s perspective concerning this problem.
. . . Wherever , by reason of the
blunders of the nation or its government, production is stationary, or does not
keep pace with consumption, the demand gradually declines, the value of the
product is less than the charges of its production; no productive exertion is
properly rewarded; profits and wages decrease; the employment of capital
becomes less advantageous and more hazardous; it is consumed piecemeal, not
through extravagance, but through necessity, and because the sources of profit
are dried up. The laboring classes experience a want of work; families before
in tolerable circumstances, are more cramped and confined; and those before in
difficulties are left altogether destitute. Depopulation, misery, and returning
barbarism, occupy the place of abundance and happiness.
No comments:
Post a Comment