The most popular version of the Austrian Business Cycle
Theory [ABCT] attempts to explain economic booms and busts as a function of central
bank intervention into the economy (For the sake of conciseness, I omit endogenous ABCT). The central bank is said to expand the
money stock, creating an unsustainable boom that distorts the relative prices
of goods and arbitrarily lengthens the structure of production (Hayek 1931; 1933; Rothbard 1963;Garrison 1999).
The lengthening occurs without an increased willingness of agents to increase
savings, and thereby lower the interest rate endogenously. As a result,
consumption does not fall to make way for an increase in goods produced
with capital and time and capital intensive techniques. As the new money makes its way from
capital intensive processes into the hands of laborers, the consumer and
producer goods industries bid up the price of inputs. Eventually, the new, more
capital intensive forms of production prove to be unprofitable, at which point the
boom turns to bust and resources are reallocated to reflect the actual time
preferences of consumers.
Two factors of enormous significance weigh on the ABCT. First, analysis typically occurs within a closed economy (Hummel 1979, 50-51). Booms and busts within a single country are assumed to be a function of the largess of the domestic central bank. Second, analysis occurs within the international gold standard. The nature of the gold standard fostered gold outflows from a nation when the central bank increased the base money stock without a concomitant increase in the nation’s gold stock. In order to stop the outflow, the central bank needed to either devalue the currency or contract the base money stock. Devaluation increased the domestic price of gold. Contraction restored the balance of exchange rates that previously existed. Underlying the entire analysis is the usual ceteris paribus condition, meaning that all other central banks are assumed to hold policy constant.
Now consider a situation where central bank “A” first expands its
money stock, only to contract it in order to stem gold outflows. The home
nation of central bank “A” might appropriately experience an ABCT-type boom and
bust, but what about other countries on the gold standard? If other central
banks only act passively – i.e., do not change their reserve ratios – then
their nations’ money stocks will also expand. When central bank “A” finally
contracts its money stock, the reverse occurs. As gold flows out from the other
nations, those central banks contract their base money stocks in order to
maintain their reserve ratios. Thus, the actions of a single central bank – if that
bank is large enough – might result in an international boom and bust. Keep in
mind that, even in a world where all but nation “A” are on 100% reserve
standards, action by central bank “A” will lead to the same result.
Note that it is the gold standard itself that necessitates the boom and bust cycle. In
a world of floating exchange rates, monetary expansion in one nation will, all
else equal, diminish the value of that nation’s currency relative to other.
Unlike under the gold standard, where an increase a nation’s domestic money
stock encourages gold to leave that nation, under floating exchange rates the
same action will lead to an increase in exports. The nation that expanded its
money stock might experience a boom as foreigners buy cheaper goods. The boom
is self-contained, only affecting other nations inasmuch as they can purchase
cheaper goods from the nation that devalued and inasmuch as they alter patterns
of productions as a result of the new stream of goods. There is no strong impulse
that drives a boom in these countries, with the caveat that the purchase of goods
from country “A” will increase demand for currency from country “A”, and symmetrically,
decrease demand for other currencies. I doubt, however, that this effect would
be large enough to stimulate a substantial boom in other countries. In this case, monetary
expansion by central bank “A” will not lead to a similar increase in demand
internationally as the responsiveness of floating exchange rates mitigate,
though not perfectly, the central bank’s impact on the real economy in each country.
Given the above analysis, I feel justified in concluding that until ABCT has accounted for the significance of different types of monetary regimes, its applicability to the modern world will remain inhibited.
No comments:
Post a Comment