When
Ludwig von Mises first expounded his theory of the business cycle in 1913,
itself a wedding of Wicksell’s natural rate hypothesis and Bohm Bawerk’s
capital theory, central bank coordination was not a problem. The Bank of
England played a leading role in determining policy and by doing so promoted
international monetary stability (Eichengreen 1987; Bordo and Macdonald 2005). This
allowed Mises to formulate a theory of the business cycle within a closed national
economy.
Mises begins his formulation by
arguing business cycles were the result of the fluctuations in credit monies
issued by private banks practicing a fractional reserve policy. By concentrating
on private banks, Mises is able to connect his business theory upon Wicksellian
foundations and lead naturally into Bohm-Bawerk’s capital theory:
If it is possible for the credit
issuing banks to reduce the rate of interest on loans below the rate determined
by the whole economic situations (Wicksell’s natürlicher Kapitalizins or
natural rate of interest), then the question arises of the particular
consequences of a situation of this kind. . . A reduction of the rate of
interest on loans must necessarily lead to a lengthening of the average period
of production. . . . But there cannot be the slightest doubt as to where this
will lead. A time must necessarily come when the means of subsistence available
for consumption are all used up although the capital goods employed in
production have not yet been transformed into consumption goods. . . . Since production
and consumption are continuous, so that every day new processes of production
are started upon and others completed, this situation does not imperil human
existence by suddenly manifesting itself as a complete lack of consumption
goods; it is merely expressed in a reduction of the quantity of goods
available. . . The market prices of consumption goods rise and those of production
fall. (1953, 359-362)
Nominal changes in money and money prices affect the structure
of production, and thereby the real economy
because relative prices, including the interest rate – the price of money across
time– have been distorted.
But can competing firms generate a business
cycle on their own and what is the range of systematic distortion that the process
of private credit expansion is able to promote? Here Mises’s argument fits well,
though not perfectly with the general old monetarist tradition (Hawtrey 1913,76)[1].
The interest rate is a lagging indicator of the real economy, so overinvestment in apparently profitable sectors is
unavoidable. Overinvestment that results from private ordering occurs within
bounds as “every bank is obliged to regulate its interest policy in accordance
with that of the others (Mises 1953, 373).” Cycles occur, but they are limited
in amplitude. Much in the same way that a flag is in stasis as it flaps in the
wind, “the money market must be subject to fluctuations (Hawtrey 1913, 76-77).”
Economic fluctuations are an inherent, yet constrained, aspect of markets.
The
scenario is complicated by the introduction of a central bank. A private bank can
lower interest rates for as long as it remains solvent. Losses, or the threat
thereof, limit the extent to which banks can allow the market rate of interest to
differ from the natural rate. Central banks can lower reserve ratios and the rate
of interest charged on loans for a longer period of time than private banks
because they face different kinds of liquidity restraints. Only when
authorities find that expansion has generated gold losses that threaten target
gold reserve ratios or worry that it has fueled too much speculation, is
contraction necessitated (Mises 1953, 390).
With a central bank, booms grow stronger and busts grow deeper as a result of manipulation of the base money stock, but mechanisms for transmitting the boom are essentially the same. An increase in the money stock distorts relative prices and arbitrarily increases the length of the structure of production. With a central bank, however, the distortion is not an emergent, uncoordinated phenomena. It is a systematic distortion resulting from the central banks privilege to create base money creation.
With a central bank, booms grow stronger and busts grow deeper as a result of manipulation of the base money stock, but mechanisms for transmitting the boom are essentially the same. An increase in the money stock distorts relative prices and arbitrarily increases the length of the structure of production. With a central bank, however, the distortion is not an emergent, uncoordinated phenomena. It is a systematic distortion resulting from the central banks privilege to create base money creation.
[1]
Hawtrey argues that it is the discrepancy between the rate of profit and the
rate of interest that drive the cycle:
If trade is for the moment stable
and the market rate of interest is equal to the profit rate, and if we suppose
that by any cause the profit rate is slightly increased, there will be an
increased demand for loans at the existing market rate. But this increased
demand for loans leads to an increase in the aggregate amount of purchasing
power, which in turn still further increases the profit rate. This process will
continue with ever accelerated force until the bankers intervene to save their
reserves by raising the rate of interest up to and above the now enhanced
profit rate. (76)
No comments:
Post a Comment